In re: Agent Orange Product Liability Litigation, 597 F.
Sup. 749 (1984) (excerpts).


	B.	The Indeterminate Plaintiff

Summers v. Tice. 33 CaL. 2d 60. L99 P2d 1 (1946)
"There is evidence that both defendants, at about the same
time or on immediateLy after the other, shot at a quail and
in doing so shot toward plaintiff who was uphill from them,
and that they knew his location.  That is sufficient from
which the trial court could conclude that they acted with
respect to the plaintiff."

In RE Agent Orange Product Liability Litigation
cite is 597 F.Sup 740 (1984)

by  Weinstein. J.:

b. The Problem of the Indeterminate Plaintiff 

	The preceding discussion assumed that although a
plaintiff would be unable to identify the manufacture of the
Agent Orange to which the veteran was exposed he or she
would be able to prove by a preponderance of the evidence
that the specific injuries from which he or she suffers were
caused by Agent Orange.  It is likely, however, that even if
plaintiffs as a class could prove that they were injured by
Agent Orange, no individual class member would be able to
prove that this or her injuries were caused by Agent Orange. 
Fore example, plaintiffs as a class may be able to show that
statistically, X% of the population not exposed to Agent
Orange could have been expected to develop soft-tissue
sarcoma, but that among those veterans who were exposed be
Agent Orange.  X + Y% suffer from soft tissue sarcoma.  If Y
is equal to or less than X and there is no meaningful
"[illegible] or anecdotal proof as to vast majority of
plaintiffs, virtually no plaintiff would be able to show by
a preponderance of the evidence that this or her cancer is
attributable to the Agent Orange rather than being part of
the "background" level of cancer in the population as a
whole.  the probability of specific cause would necessarily
be less than 50% based upon the evidence submitted.

(1) Scope of the Problem

	The problem just noted is one that has received a
significant amount of scholarly discussion a well as some
attention from the United States Congress.

	Because of the rarity of the situation until recently
scant attention has been given to the issue by the courts. 
There has apparently been only one other mass exposure
decision that has discussed the indeterminate plaintiff
problem explicitly. viz, Allen v. United States, 588 F. Sup
247 (D. Utah 1964), a case where [illegible] was claimed as
a result of radioactive exposure from testing of atomic
explosive devices.

	In our complex industrialized society it is
unfortunately possible that some products used on a
widespread scale will cause significant harm to the public. 
While it may be possible to prove, through the use of such
proof as laboratory tests on animals and epidemiological
evidence, that such harm -- for example cancer -- can be
"caused" by a particular substance, it may be impossible to
pinpoint which particular person's cancer would have
occurred naturally and which would not have occurred but for
exposure to the substance.

	Epidemiological statistics, which constitute the best
(if not the sole) available evidence in mass exposure cases,
can only attribute a proportion of  the disease incidence in
the population to each potential source . . . .  But
. . . it is impossible to pinpoint the actual source of the
disease afflicting any specific member of the exposed
population.

	Rosenberg.  The Causal Connection in Mass Exposure
Cases:  A "Public Law" Vision of the Tort System, 97 Harv.
L. Rev. 849 856-57 (1984) (footnotes omitted).

	In two of the largest and most widely publicized mass
tort litigations, those involving DES and asbestos, the
problem outlined above does not pose a serious obstacle
since at least some of the damage caused by the harmful
substance was it has been claimed, unique to that substance. 
Adenosis and clear cell adenocarcinoma of the vagina and
uterus, the conditions associated with DES, are, it is said,
almost unknown among women whose mothers had not taken DES. 
Note, DES and a Proposed Theory of Enterprise Liability, 46
Fordham L.Rev. 963, 965 (1978).  The situation is similar,
in the asbestos litigation, albeit to a lesser extent. 
Although lung cancer is associated with cigarette smoking
and other factors as well as asbestos exposure and
mesothelioma may have causes other than asbestos is alleged
to be uniquely associated with asbestos exposure.  Barel v.
Fiberboard Paper Products Corp., 493 F.2d 1076,1083 (5th
Cir. 1973), cert denied, 419 U.S. 869, 96 S.Ct. 127, 42
L.Ed.2d 107 (1974). In most other mass exposure cases,
however, the harm caused by the toxic substance is
indistinguishable from the naturally occurring disease or
condition.
	See Dore.  A Commentary on the Use of Epidemiological
Evidence in Demonstrating Cause-in-Fact, 7 Har.Envtl.L.Rev
429, 437 (1983); Solomons, Workers' Compensation for
Occupational Disease Victims: Federal Standards and
Threshold Problems, 41 Alb.L.Rev. 195, 199 (1977),

	The recent case of Allen v. United States, 588 F. Sup.
247 (D.Utah 1984), illustrates the problem well.  Plaintiffs
claimed that they developed various forms of cancer as a
result of their exposure to radiation from nuclear
explosions.  While some forms of cancer can, it is
contended, with some certainty be attributed to factors
other than exposure to radiation, many others "cannot be
distinguished from cancer of the same organ arising from
. . . unknown cases". i.e., the 'background' cancers.  J.
Gofman, Radiation and Human Health 59 (1981), quoted in
Allen v. United States, 588 F. Sup at 406.  The statistical
evidence in Allen apparently made it clear that there was a
strong positive association between exposure to low-level
ionizing radiation, presumably the result of atomic
explosions, and various forms of cancer suffered by
plaintiffs.  Thus, the Allen case has some of the
characteristics of the DES and asbestos cases in addition to
persuasive statistical correlations.

(2)  Preponderance Rule

	Even if there were near certainty as to general
causation, if there were significant uncertainty as to
individual causation, traditional tort principles would
dictate that causation be determined on a case-by-case basis
using the preponderance-of-the-evidence rule.  Santosky v.
Kramer, 455 U.S. 745, 755, 102 S. Ct. 1388, 1395 71 L.Ed.2d
599 (1982); W. Prosser, Handbook of the Law of Torts, 206-09
(1971); Kaplan, Decision Theory and the Fact Finding
Process, 20 Stan. L. Rev. 1065, 1072 (1968). The rule
provides as "'all or nothing' approach, whereby [assuming
all other elements of the cause of action are proven], the
plaintiff becomes entitled to full compensation for those
 . . . damages that are proved to be 'probable' (a greater
than 50 percent chance), but is not entitled to any
compensation if the proof does not establish a greater than
50 percent chance."  Jackson v. John-Manville Sales Corp.,
727 F.2d 506, 516 (5th Cir. 1984).
	Under the "strong" version of the preponderance rule,
statistical correlations alone indicating that the
probability of causation exceeds fifty percent are
insufficient some "particularistic" or anecdotal evidence,
that is, "proof that can provide direct and actual knowledge
of the causal relationship between the defendant's tortious
conduct and the plaintiff's injury." is required.

	As Professor Jaffee has put it,

	If all that can be said is that there are 55 chances of
negligence out of 100, that is not enough.  There must
be a rational, i.e., evidentiary basis on which the
jury can choose the competing probabilities.  If there
is not, the finding will be based . . . on mere
speculation and conjecture.

Jaffee, Res. Ipea Loquitur Vindicated, I Buffalo L.Rev. 1, 4
(1951).  The "weak" version of the preponderance rule would
allow a verdict solely on statistical evidence; the "all-or-
nothing" approach converts the statistical probability into
a legally absolute finding that the causal connection did or
did not exist in the case.  C. McCormick, Handbook on the
Law of Damages, 118 (1935).  The justification for not
requiring "particularistic" or anecdotal evidence is
trenchantly and accurately stated by Professor Rosenberg:

	[T]he entire notion that "particularistic" evidence
differs in some significant qualitative way from
statistical evidence must be questioned.  The concept
of "particularistic" evidence suggests that there
exists a form of proof that can provide direct and
actual knowledge of the causal relationship between the
defendant's tortious conduct and the plaintiff's
injury.  "Particularistic" evidence, however, is in
fact no less probabilistic than is the statistical
evidence that   courts purport show . . .
"Particularistic" evidence offers nothing more than a
basis for conclusions about a perceived balance of
probabilities.

Rosenberg, supra, 97 Har.L.Rev. at 870 (footnotes omitted). 
Except where it appears that the absence of anecdotal
evidence may be due to spoliation, probabilities based upon
quantitative analysis should support a recovery.  See e.g.,
E.M. Morgan & J.M. Maguire, Cases and Materials on Evidence,
39 (7th ed. 1983).
	There would appear to be little harm in retaining the
requirement for "particularistic" evidence of causation in
sporadic accident cases since such evidence is almost always
available in such litigation.  In mass exposure cases,
however, where the chance that there would be
particularistic evidence is in most cases quite small, the
consequence of retaining the requirement might be to allow
defendants whom, it is virtually certain, have injured
thousands of people and caused billions of dollars in
damage, be [illegible] liability.  Because of this
[illegible] fact that "particularistic evidence . . . is
. . . no less probabilistic than . . . statistical
evidence," the "weak" version of the preponderance rule
appears to be the preferable standard to apply in mass
exposure cases--particularly where, as here, all claimants
and defendants are jointed in one suit.

(a) Application of the Preponderance Rule to Mass Exposure
Cases

	Conventional application of the "weak" version of the
preponderance rule would dictate that, if the toxic
substance caused the indigence of the injury to rise more
than 100% above the "background" level, each plaintiff
exposed t the substance could recover if he or she is
suffering from that type of injury.  If, however, to put it
in somewhat graphic, albeit artificial terms, the incidence
rose only 100% of less, no plaintiff could recover--i.e.,
the probability of specific causation would not be more than
50%.

	Where a plaintiff's injuries result from a series of
unrelated sporadic accidents, this "all-or-nothing" rule is
justifiably rationalized on the ground that it is the
fairest and most efficient result.  In mass exposure cases,
however, this all-or-nothing rule results in either a
tortious defendant being relieved of all liability or
overcompensation to many plaintiffs and a crushing liability
on the defendant.  These results are especially troublesome
because, unlike the sporadic accident cases, it may be
possible to ascertain with a fair degree of assurance that
the defendant did cause damage, and, albeit with somewhat
less certainty, the total amount of that damage.
	The problem is both illustrated and further compounded
by the fact that lack of precision in the data and models
used may cause the range of the probabilities estimated by
the statistical proof to lie on either or other sides of the
100% line.  Because the statistical proof will almost never
be as complete or as free from confounding factors as
desirable, it may be possible to infer, for example, that
the toxic substance caused the incidence to rise over the
background level somewhere between 80 and 120%.  See e.g.,
Allen v. United States, 588 F.Sup 247, 438, 439 n. 197
(D.Utah 1984) (noting significant variation in experts
interpretations of statistical evidence relating to the
likelihood that plaintiff's cancer was caused by exposure to
radiation).  Moreover, issues of credibility and varying
inferences drawn by the trier based upon varying assessments
of probative force may cause reasonable people to assess
these percentages in a range from almost zero to well over
120.  See, e.g., E.M. Morgan & J.M. Maguire, Cases and
Materials on Evidence, ch. 1 (7th ed. 1983).

	Under the traditional application of the preponderance
rule, whether individual plaintiffs recover will depend on
where the probability percentage line is drawn despite the
fact that a reasonable trier would conclude that a large
proportion of the plaintiffs were injured by the defendant
and a large number were not.  Even if the statistical
increase attributed to the substance in question is just a
few percentage points, if statistical theory supports a
finding of correlation there is no reason why the industry
as a whole should not pay for the damages it probably
caused.

	A simple hypothetical will illustrate why too heavy a
burden should not be placed on plaintiffs by requiring a
high percentage or incidence of a disease to be attributable
to a particular product.  Let us assume that there are 10
manufacturers and a population of 10 million persons exposed
to their product.  Assume that among this population 1,000
cancers of a certain type could be expected, but that 1,100
exist, and that this increase is "statistically
significant," permitting a reasonable conclusion that 100
cancers are due to the product of the manufacturers.  In the
absence of other evidence, it might be argued that as to any
one of the 1100 there is only a chance of about 9%
(100/1100) that the product caused the cancer.  Under
traditional tort principles no plaintiff could recover.
(b)  Inadequacy of Individualized Solutions

	Any attempt to resolve the problem on a plaintiff-by-
plaintiff basis cannot be fully satisfactory.  The solution
that would most readily suggest itself is a burden shifting
approach, analogous to that used in the indeterminate
defendant situation already discussed.  Allen v. United
States provides a good example of how burden-shifting would
be applied in an indeterminate plaintiff case.  A plaintiff
must show that the defendant, in that case the United
States, negligently put "an identifiable population group"
of which he was a member at "increased risk" and that his
injury is consistent with having been caused by the hazard
to which he has been negligently subjected, such consistency
having been demonstrated by substantial, appropriate,
persuasive and connecting factors . . . .

Allen, 588 F. Sup. at 415.  At that point, the burden shifts
to the defendant which will be held liable unless it can
offer "persuasive proof" of noncausation.  Id.

	Generally courts have shifted the burden to the
defendant to prove that it was not responsible for
plaintiff's injury only in sporadic accident cases where it
was certain that one of a very limited number of defendants
injured the plaintiff, see, e.g., Summers v. Rice, 33 Cal.2d
80, 199 P.2d (86, 154 P.2d 687 (1944), or in mass exposure
cases where general causation was certain and liability was
apportioned in accordance with some market share theory. 
See. r.g., Sindell v. Abbott Laboratories, 26 Cal.3d 588,
607 P.2d 924, 163 Cal.Rptr. 132, cert. denied, 449 U.S. 912,
101 S.Ct. 285, 66 L.Ed.2d 140 (1980), Copeland v. Celotex
Corp., 447 So.2d 908 (Fla.App. 1984).  But see Abel v. Eli
Lilly & Co., 418 Mich. 311, 343 N.W.2d 164 (1984) (joint and
several liability in DES cases).

	Shifting the burden of proof in such cases will, at
least theoretically, not result in crushing liability for
the defendant either because the litigation only involves a
sporadic accident, as in Summers and Ybarra, or because the
defendant will only be held liable for the amount of damage
it caused based on market share--although as indicated
above, there may be practical problems in defining market
share.  By contrasts, shifting the burden of proof in the
indeterminate plaintiff situation could result in liability
far out of proportion to damage caused.  It is not helpful
in most situations to say that the defendant will not be
liable for "those harms which [he] can reasonably prove were
not in fat a consequence of his risk-creating, negligent
conduct," Allen, 588 F.Sup. at 415, since, were such
individualized proof available, there would have been no
need to shift the bur-
(3)  Possible Solution in Class Action

	Since the problem results from plaintiff-by-plaintiff
methods of adjudication, one solution is to try all
plaintiffs' claims together in a class action thereby
arriving at a single, class-wide determination of the total
harm to the community of plaintiffs.  Given the necessarily
heavy reliance on statistical evidence in mass exposure
cases, such a determination seems feasible.  The defendant
would then be liable to each exposed plaintiff for a pro
rate share of that plaintiff's injuries.

	This approach can be illustrated using the hypothetical
given above.  Suppose all 1,100 of those who were exposed to
the harmful substance and who developed the cancer in the
example join in a class action against all 10 manufacturers. 
Let us say that damages average $1,000,000 per cancer.  A
recovery of $100,000,000 (100 x $1,000,000) in favor of the
class would be allowed with the percentage of the ward to be
paid by each manufacturer depending on the toxicity of its
product.  For example, if a company produced only 20% of the
substance in question but, because of the greater toxicity
of its product, likely caused 60% of the harm, it would
contribute 60% of the total amount.  If accurate records are
available on the composition of each defendant's product,
that analysis should be possible.

	Since no plaintiff can show that his or her cancer was
caused by any one of the defendants [illegible] giving each
a recovery of about $90,000.  While any plaintiff might feel
that his or her recovery denigrated the degree of harm, the
alternative of receiving nothing is far worse.  The latter
is, of course, the necessary result in any plaintiff's
individual suit.  Moreover, the deterrent effect of this
result on producers would be significant.  See Delgado,
Beyond Sindell: Relaxation of Cause-in-Fact rules for
Indeterminate Plaintiffs, 70 Cal.L.Re. 881, 893 (1982).

	If the number of cases were only 1,050, most
statisticians would say the difference was not statistically
significant and a court using the pro rata approach might
find that the defendant is not legally responsible for any
of the increased incidence.  But we

Allen v. United States, 588 F.Sup. at 416-17 (noting that
although increased incidence might be deemed "insignificant"
by a scientists or statistician, it may well be that it "is
still far more likely than not" that "the observed increase
is related to its hypothetical cause rather than mere
chance").  (In the numbers used, the standard deviation
could be computed by square root as the square root of 1000
equals 31.6.  Two standard deviations--a rough test of
statistical significance often used in the law--is 63.2; 50
is less than two standard deviations.  Yet, assuming the 100
variation of the hypothetical (more than 3 standard
deviations), the law should nonetheless attribute to the
defendants al 100 additional cancers, not just 100 minus 63
or 37 (the total variation less two standard deviations). 
As a matter of rough justice, once legal responsibility for
the increased incidence is found, it is sounder to attribute
all 100 cases to the defendant, even though a substantial
number of these cases may be random variations with no
reasonable assurance that they are attributable to the
defendants' activities.  There is, of course, also the
possibility that more than 100 cases were "caused by"
defendant's activities since the figure properly
attributable to background cancer incidence might have been
less than 1000.  We are in a different world of proof than
that of the archetypical smoking gun.  We must make the best
estimates of probability that we can using the help of
experts such as statisticians and our own common sense and
experience with the real universe.

	Putting a dollar amount on the damages suffered by
individual plaintiffs is, from a real-world standpoint, a
critical part of the solution.  If the judicial and monetary
economies of the class action are not to be lost through
lengthy and expensive individual trials on damages, some
mechanism must be devised to decide damage claims without
the need for a full-fledged trial of reach plaintiff.  As
Professor rosenberg points out, "[p]ossibly the greatest
source of litigation expense [in mass exposure tort
litigation] is the individual assessment and distribution of
damages that must follow trial of common liability
question."  Rosenberg, supra, 97 Harv.L.Rev. at 916.

	How individualized such a mechanism would have to be
depends on (1) the size of the individual claim and (2) what
the variations between plaintiffs are in the nature of the
claims: the smaller the individual claim and the less the
variation, the more generalized the process can be.  If
their claims are for one type of injury, a compensation
schedule to calculate average loss could be developed based
on sampling techniques.  See Manual for Complex Litigation
2.712 at 116-18 (1982).  If a number of different
[illegible]
	Every effort should be made to reduce questions of fact
to a bare minimum.  A preferred solution is to pay claims on
a fixed and somewhat arbitrary schedule using a ministerial
agency as is donee with the Medicaid and Medicare programs
where disbursements are made by insurance agencies acting
for the United States.

	No matter what system is used the purpose is to hold a
defendant liable for no more than the aggregate loss fairly
attributable to its tortious conduct.  As long as that goal
is met a defendant can have not valid objection that its
rights have been violated.

(a)  Analogy and Precedent

	(i) The Employment Discrimination Cases

	It was noted above that courts have only recently been
faced with fact patterns involving mass exposure and
indeterminate plaintiffs.  That is not to say that there is
no relevant guidance or precedent.  In the employment
discrimination area courts have long dealt with cases
involving a defendant who through his acts exposed an entire
class to harm resulting in an injured class with
indeterminate plaintiffs.  The solutions developed and the
reasoning used by some courts in those cases parallel that
outlined above for the mass exposure fact patterns.  The
defendant employer has acted wrongfully through his
discriminatory acts.  As here, however, it is often
impossible to prove whether the plaintiff's condition, in
that case the lower salary or lack of promotion or
employment, is due to the defendant's wrongful acts or
whether it would have occurred even absent in the
discriminatory acts.  For example, if class members
outnumber the openings for job promotions it is undeniable
that some class members would not have been promoted even if
there had been no discrimination.  The solution adopted by
some courts parallels the pro rate approach suggested above
for mass exposure cases: awards are based on the "average"
pay and rank of a group of employees, not injured by
discrimination, comparable in all other material respects,
such as ability and length of employment.

	In the employment discrimination cases the
impossibility of identifying individual class members is
recognized.  The courts have noted that although "[t]here is
no way of determining which jobs the class members would
have . . . obtained if [the] discriminatory [system] . . .
had not been in existence [because] [c]lass members
outnumber promotions cannot be awarded."  [i]t does not
follow that back pay claims based on promotions cannot be
awarded."  Pettway v. American Cast Iron Pipe Co, 494 F.2d
211, 260 (5th Cir. 1974).  "Doubts about which individuals
. . . would have been promoted" call for "a class approach." 
Id. at 261 n. 150.
[T]he total award for the entire class would be determined. 
At that point, individual claims would be calculated on pro
rata shares for those workers of similar ability and
seniority claiming the same position, possibly eliminating
the necessity of deciding which one of many employees would
have obtained the position but for the discrimination.

Id. at 263 n. 154.  Here, too, the "total [injury] to the
entire class [can] be determined" and, "[a]t that point,
individual claims could be calculated on pro rata shares for
those" exposed plaintiffs "claiming the same" injury,
"eliminating the necessity [illegible] which one of many"
plaintiffs would not have developed the injury "but for" the
exposure. Cf. P.J. Spiegelman, Court-Ordered Hiring Quotas
After Stotts: A Narrative on the Role of Feminine And
Masculine Coives in the Legal Process, 31ff, (1984).

	The "Agent Orange" case is especially well-suited to
the application of such an approach.  Not only are all
producers of the allegedly harmful substance before the
court, but so is almost every person allegedly injured who
could now be before an American court.  While, for example,
American civilians and Vietnamese residents may have been
injured, the statutes of limitations have probable run on
their claims.

(iii)  Consumer Class Actions

	There is another area in which courts have dealt with
fact patterns involving large numbers of injured plaintiffs
where it is possible to determine the damage on a class-wide
basis, but it is not feasible to determine the amount of
damage suffered by each class member and to compensate him
for that damage.  Such situations arise where defendants
have sold a product to or performed a service for, numerous
persons, sometimes ranging into the millions and have
illegally overcharged many or all of those persons.  While
each class member's damages are often quite small, the
defendant has reaped a substantial wrongful gain.  Because
most plaintiffs will not come forward to claim their damages
due to the small amounts involved, courts are faced with the
choice of either allowing the defendant to keep the wrongful
gain, or as a number of courts have done, to distribute the
damages to as many members of the class as is practicable. 
See, for example, Eisen v. Carlisle & Jacquelin, 52 F.R.D.
253 (S.D.N.Y. 1971), where the defendant brokerage firms
were accused of monopolizing odd-lot trading on the New York
Stock exchange and of charging excessively high brokerage
commissions.  The court in Eisen suggested that one possible
method of distributing the damages would be to set up "a
fund equivalent to the amount of unclaimed damages . . . and
[to reduce] the odd-lot differential . . . in an amount
determined reasonable by the court until such time as the
fund is depleted."  Eisen, 52 F.R.D. at 265.

	This type of solution is sometimes referred to as a
"fluid recovery," i.e., one which avoids the requirement of
individual identification of class members and individual
distribution of damages, in favor of a remedy for the next
best class, e.g., macro-statistical description of the class
harm remedied by future reduction in prices or rates charged
by the defendant.

3B J.W. Moore, Moore's Federal Practice 23.45(4.-4)(1984).
	As in the solution proposed for the indeterminate
plaintiff situation, "the damage issue [is tried] only
once," with the result that "the amount of damages arrived
at is likely to correspond to the total injury inflicted by
defendant or the extent of its "unjust enrichment."  7A C.
Wright & A. Miller, Federal Practice and Procedure 1784
(1972).  Courts must choose between compensating large
numbers of demonstrably injured people in an imperfect
manner or not compensating them at all.

	It should be emphasized that we are not concluding that
the analysis and solutions is the employment discrimination
and consumer class action cases compel a similar result in
the mass exposure cases.  There are obviously differences
between the fact patterns.  It also appears undisputed that
no court, except perhaps as part of a settlement, has ever
applied the pro rata plan in mass exposure cases.  Given the
present reluctance of many courts to certify mass tort
litigations as class actions, it is likely that courts, at
least for a number of years, will not be faced with a
request to adopt such an approach.  Se the analysis of cases
in re "Agent Orange" Product Liability Litigation, 100
F.R.D. 718 (E.D.N.Y. 1983), mandamus denied, 725 F.2d 858
(2d Cir. cert. denied -- U.S. --, 104 S. Ct. 1417, 79
L.Ed.2d 743 (1984).  The application of such a scheme,
although consistent with the accepted goals of tort law,
requires a fundamental rethinking of a number of well
established legal concepts.  Nevertheless, the employment
discrimination and consumer class action cases reflect a
pragmatic judicial solution to analogous problems, providing
a clue to the direction courts may properly take in
resolving mass exposure cases.

(b) Practical Advantages of a Class-wide Solution

	In addition to the strong legal arguments in favor of
dealing with the indeterminate plaintiff fact pattern in a
class action, there are strong practical considerations as
well.  The most important of these was already noted in
passing--namely, the judicial and economic efficiencies that
result from class-wide treatment.  This factor has already
been alluded to in the opinion certifying plaintiffs as a
class.  See In re "Agent Orange" Product Liability
Litigation, 100 F.R.D. 718 (E.D.N.Y. 1983).
	Although recent studies suggest that defendants in mass
tort cases spend more than plaintiffs do for legal services,
see. J. Kahalik, P. Ebener, W. Reistiner & M. Shanley, Costs
of Asbestos Litigation, Rand Corp.  The Institute for Civil
Justice, July 1988), defendants, often large corporations,
are usually better able to bear the cost of litigating
individual suits than are plaintiffs' attorneys who are
generally financing the litigation out of their own pockets. 
A class action, by allowing plaintiffs' claims at once,
should not only reduce the overall cost of the litigation
significantly but should tend to equalize the odds between
the two sides. Cf. Note.  The Inapplicability of Traditional
Tort Analysis to Environmental Risks:  The Example of Toxic
Waste Pollution Victim Compensation, 35 Stan.L.Rev. 575, 586
(1983).  A class action would also facilitate settlement by
allowing defendants to buy their peace with all of the
plaintiffs at once.  See, e.g., "Agent Orange,: 100 F.R.D.
at 721.  One the negative side, making it easier to sue may
increase the possibility of obtaining unjustified
settlements by a form of legal coercion.

	By litigating the issue of liability only once courts
can avoid the danger of inconsistent verdicts that could
easily result in those cases where the increased incidence
of the disease hovers around 100%.  The danger is especially
acute given the number of possible confounding factors and
the fact that [illegible] data and statistical studies are
rarely as reliable and complete as they ideally could be. 
It is, therefore, altogether possible that different
conclusions on similar or identical evidence despite the
fact that their interpretations of the evidence might not
differ appreciably.

	The transaction costs of obtaining a remedy are a
proper consideration in determining substantive law.  If
much of a recovery will go to attorneys and experts rather
than to those injured, then traditional tort remedies may be
so ineffective as to put in doubt their utility in
particular types of cases.  Punishment of defendants who
cause harm and deterrence of future harmful conduct is by-
product of the traditional tort system, but it should not
independently furnish the rationale for private civil 
litigation. Where, therefore, the transaction costs of 
obtaining a remedy for a class are much less per dollar 
recovered than they would be in a case-by-case recovery, the 
class actionmay, as a matter of policy, be the only 
reasonable route to recovery.  Added to the costs to 
defendants and plaintiffs must be the cost to the public and 
the courts in burdening the system with large numbers of 
private, individual claims.  Thus, while the class action is 
deemed procedural and distinct from substantive considerations 
for most purposes, it may become, in a case like "Agent Orange," 
the only practicable way to secure a remedy.